Richard Cantillon
Born1680s[1]
Died1734[2] (aged about 54)
EraAge of Reason
RegionWestern philosophy
SchoolPhysiocracy
Main interests
Political economy
Notable ideas
Entrepreneur as risk-bearer,
monetary theory,
spatial economics,
theory of population growth,
cause and effect methodology
Signature

Richard Cantillon (French: [kɑ̃tijɔ̃]; 1680s May 1734) was an Irish-French economist and author of Essai Sur La Nature Du Commerce En Général (Essay on the Nature of Trade in General), a book considered by William Stanley Jevons to be the "cradle of political economy".[3] Although little information exists on Cantillon's life, it is known that he became a successful banker and merchant at an early age. His success was largely derived from the political and business connections he made through his family and through an early employer, James Brydges. During the late 1710s and early 1720s, Cantillon speculated in, and later helped fund, John Law's Mississippi Company, from which he acquired great wealth. However, his success came at a cost to his debtors, who pursued him with lawsuits, criminal charges, and even murder plots until his death in 1734.

Essai remains Cantillon's only surviving contribution to economics. It was written around 1730 and circulated widely in manuscript form, but was not published until 1755. His work was translated into Spanish by Gaspar Melchor de Jovellanos, probably in the late 1770s, and considered essential reading for political economy. Despite having much influence on the early development of the physiocrat and classical schools of thought, Essai was largely forgotten until its rediscovery by Jevons in the late 19th century.[4] Cantillon was influenced by his experiences as a banker, and especially by the speculative bubble of John Law's Mississippi Company. He was also heavily influenced by prior economists, especially William Petty.

Essai is considered the first complete treatise on economics, with numerous contributions to the science. These contributions include: his cause and effect methodology, monetary theories, his conception of the entrepreneur as a risk-bearer, and the development of spatial economics. Cantillon's Essai had significant influence on the early development of political economy, including the works of Adam Smith, Anne Turgot, Jean-Baptiste Say, Frédéric Bastiat and François Quesnay.[5]

Biography

While details regarding Richard Cantillon's life are scarce,[6] it is thought that he was born sometime during the 1680s in County Kerry, Ireland.[1][5] He was son to land-owner Richard Cantillon of Ballyheigue.[7] Sometime in the middle of the first decade of the 18th century Cantillon moved to France, where he attained French citizenship.[8] By 1711, Cantillon found himself in the employment of British Paymaster General James Brydges, in Spain, where he organised payments to British prisoners of war during the War of Spanish Succession.[9] Cantillon remained in Spain until 1714, cultivating a number of business and political connections, before returning to Paris.[10] Cantillon then became involved in the banking industry working for a cousin, who at that time was lead-correspondent of the Parisian branch of a family bank.[11] Two years later, thanks in large part to financial backing by James Brydges, Cantillon bought his cousin out and attained ownership of the bank.[12] Given the financial and political connections Cantillon was able to attain both through his family[13] and through James Brydges, Cantillon proved a fairly successful banker, specialising in money transfers between Paris and London.[14]

At this time, Cantillon became involved with British mercantilist John Law through the Mississippi Company.[15] Based on the monetary theory proposed by William Potter in his 1650 tract The Key of Wealth,[16] John Law posited that increases in the money supply would lead to the employment of unused land and labour, leading to higher productivity.[17] In 1716, the French government granted him both permission to found the Banque Générale and virtual monopoly over the right to develop French territories in North America, named the Mississippi Company. In return, Law promised the French government to finance its debt at low rates of interest.[18] Law began a financial speculative bubble by selling shares of the Mississippi Company, using the Banque Générale's virtual monopoly on the issue of bank notes to finance his investors.[19]

Richard Cantillon amassed a great fortune from his speculation, buying Mississippi Company shares early and selling them later at higher prices, even though he had stated he believed Law's "scheme was unsound and was bound to fail."[20] Cantillon's financial success and growing influence caused friction in his relationship with John Law, and sometime thereafter Law threatened to imprison Cantillon if the latter did not leave France within twenty-four hours.[21] Cantillon replied: "I shall not go away; but I will make your system succeed."[21] To that end, in 1718 Law, Cantillon, and wealthy speculator Joseph Gage formed a private company centred on financing further speculation in North American real estate.[22]

In 1719, Cantillon left Paris for Amsterdam, returning briefly in early 1720. Lending in Paris, Cantillon had outlying debt repaid to him in London and Amsterdam.[23] With the collapse of the "Mississippi bubble", Cantillon was able to collect on debt accruing high rates of interest.[24] Most of his debtors had suffered financial damage in the bubble collapse and blamed Cantillon—until his death, Cantillon was involved in countless lawsuits filed by his debtors, leading to a number of murder plots and criminal accusations.[25]

On 16 February 1722, Cantillon married Mary Mahony, daughter of Count Daniel O'Mahony—a wealthy merchant and former Irish general—spending much of the remainder of the 1720s travelling throughout Europe with his wife.[26] Cantillon and Mary had two children, a son who died at an early age and a daughter, Henrietta,[27] wife successively of the 3rd Earl of Stafford and the 1st Earl of Farnham. Although he frequently returned to Paris between 1729 and 1733, his permanent residence was in London.[28] In May 1734, his residence in London was burned to the ground, and it is generally assumed that Cantillon died in the fire.[2] While the fire's causes are unclear, the most widely accepted theory is that Cantillon was murdered.[29] One of Cantillon's biographers, Antoine Murphy, has advanced the alternative theory that Cantillon staged his own death to escape the harassment of his debtors, appearing in Suriname under the name Chevalier de Louvigny.[30]

Contributions to economics

Although there is evidence that Richard Cantillon wrote a wide variety of manuscripts, only his Essai Sur La Nature Du Commerce En Général (abbreviated Essai) survives.[5][31] Written in 1730,[32] it was published in French in 1755,[33] and was translated into English by Henry Higgs in 1932.[34] Evidence suggests that Essai had tremendous influence on the early development of economic science. However, Cantillon's treatise was largely neglected during the 19th century.[4] In the late 19th century it was "rediscovered" by William Stanley Jevons, who considered it the "cradle of political economy".[3] Since then, Cantillon's Essai has received growing attention. Essai is considered the first complete treatise on economic theory,[35] and Cantillon has been called the "father of enterprise economics".[5][36]

William Petty is considered to be one of Richard Cantillon's greatest influences.[37]

One of the greatest influences on Cantillon's writing was English economist William Petty and his 1662 tract Treatise on Taxes.[38] Although Petty provided much of the groundwork for Cantillon's Essai,[37] Anthony Brewer argues that Petty's influence has been overstated.[39] Apart from Petty, other possible influences on Cantillon include John Locke,[40] Cicero, Livy, Pliny the Elder, Pliny the Younger, Charles Davenant, Edmond Halley, Isaac Newton, Sébastien Le Prestre de Vauban, and Jean Boisard.[41] Cantillon's involvement in John Law's speculative bubble proved invaluable and likely heavily influenced his insight on the relationship between increases in the supply of money, price, and production.[42]

Methodology

Cantillon's Essai is written using a distinctive causal methodology, separating Cantillon from his mercantilist predecessors.[5][43] Essai is peppered with the word "natural", which in the case of Cantillon's treatise is meant to imply a cause and effect relationship between economic actions and their underlying (i.e. causing) phenomena.[44] Economist Murray Rothbard credits Cantillon with being one of the first theorists to isolate economic phenomena with simple models, where otherwise-uncontrollable variables can be fixed.[45] Cantillon made frequent use of the concept of ceteris paribus throughout Essai in an attempt to neglect independent variables.[46] Furthermore, he is credited with employing a methodology similar to Carl Menger's methodological individualism,[47] by deducing complex phenomena from simple observations.[48]

A cause and effect methodology led to a relatively value-free approach to economic science, in which Cantillon was uninterested in the merit of any particular economic action or phenomenon, focusing rather on the explanation of relationships.[49] This led Cantillon to separate economic science from politics and ethics to a greater degree than previous mercantilist writers.[45] This has led to disputes on whether Cantillon can justly be considered a mercantilist or one of the first anti-mercantilists,[50] given that Cantillon often cited government-manipulated trade surpluses and specie accumulation as positive economic stimuli.[51] Others argue that in instances where Cantillon is thought to have supported certain mercantilist policies, he actually provided a more neutral analysis by explicitly stating possible limitations of mercantilist policies.[52]

Monetary theory

Differences between prior mercantilists and Cantillon arise early in Essai, regarding the origins of wealth and price formation on the market.[53] Cantillon distinguishes between wealth and money, considering wealth in itself "nothing but the food, conveniences, and pleasures of life."[54] While Cantillon advocated an "intrinsic" theory of value, based on the input of land and labour (cost of production),[55] he is considered to have touched upon a subjective theory of value.[56] Cantillon held that market prices are not immediately decided by intrinsic value, but are derived from supply and demand.[57] He considered market prices to be derived by comparing supply, the quantity of a particular good in a particular market, to demand, the quantity of money brought to be exchanged.[58] Believing market prices to tend towards the intrinsic value of a good, Cantillon may have also originated the uniformity-of-profit principle—changes in the market price of a good may lead to changes in supply, reflecting a rise or fall in profit.[59]

Rendition of Cantillon's primitive circular flow model[60]

In Essai, Cantillon provided an advanced version of John Locke's quantity theory of money, focusing on relative inflation and the velocity of money.[61] Cantillon suggested that inflation occurs gradually and that the new supply of money has a localised effect on inflation, effectively originating the concept of non-neutral money.[62] Furthermore, he posited that the original recipients of new money enjoy higher standards of living at the expense of later recipients.[63] The concept of relative inflation, or a disproportionate rise in prices among different goods in an economy, is now known as the Cantillon Effect.[64][65] Cantillon also considered changes in the velocity of money (quantity of exchanges made within a specific amount of time) influential on prices, although not to the same degree as changes in the quantity of money.[66] While he believed that the money supply consisted only of specie, he conceded that increases in money substitutes—or bank notes—could affect prices by effectively increasing the velocity of circulating of deposited specie.[67] Apart from distinguishing money from money substitute, he also distinguished between bank notes offered as receipts for specie deposits and bank notes circulating beyond the quantity of specie—or fiduciary media—suggesting that the volume of fiduciary media is strictly limited by people's confidence in its redeemability.[68] He considered fiduciary media a useful tool to abate the downward pressure that hoarding of specie has on the velocity of money.[69]

Addressing the mercantilist belief that monetary intervention could cause a perpetually favourable balance of trade, Cantillon developed a specie-flow mechanism foreshadowing future international monetary equilibrium theories.[70] He suggested that in countries with a high quantity of money in circulation, prices will increase and therefore become less competitive in relation to countries where there is a relative scarcity of money.[71] Thus, Cantillon also held that increases in the supply of money, regardless of the source, cause increases in the price level and therefore reduce the competitiveness of a particular nation's industry in relation to a nation with lower prices.[72] However, Cantillon did not believe that international markets tended toward equilibrium, and instead suggested that government hoard specie to avoid rising prices and falling competitiveness.[70] Furthermore, he suggested that a favourable balance of trade can be maintained by offering a better product and retaining qualitative competitiveness.[73] Cantillon's preference towards a favourable balance of trade possibly stemmed from the mercantilist belief in exchange being a zero-sum game, in which one party gains at the expense of another.[74]

A relatively advanced theory of interest is also presented.[75] Cantillon believed that interest originates from the need of borrowers for capital and from the fear of loss of the lenders, meaning that borrowers have to recompense lenders for the risk of the possible insolvency of the debtor.[76] In turn, interest is paid out of earned profits originating from the return on invested capital.[77] While previously it was believed that the rate of interest varied inversely to the quantity of money, Cantillon posited that the rate of interest was determined by the supply and demand on the loanable funds market[78]—an insight usually attributed to Scottish philosopher David Hume.[79] As such, while saved money impacts the rate of interest, new money that is instead used for consumption does not; Cantillon's theory of interest is therefore similar to John Maynard Keynes's liquidity preference theory.[80]

Other contributions

Traditionally, it is Jean-Baptiste Say who is credited for coining the word and advancing the concept of the entrepreneur, but in fact it was Cantillon who first introduced the term in Essai.[5][81] Cantillon divided society into two principal classes—fixed income wage-earners and non-fixed income earners.[82] Entrepreneurs, according to Cantillon, are non-fixed income earners who pay known costs of production but earn uncertain incomes,[83] due to the speculative nature of pandering to an unknown demand for their product.[84] Cantillon, while providing the foundations, did not develop a dedicated theory of uncertainty—the topic was not revisited until the 20th century, by Ludwig von Mises, Frank Knight, and John Maynard Keynes, among others.[85] Furthermore, unlike later theories of entrepreneurship which saw the entrepreneur as a disruptive force, Cantillon anticipated the belief that the entrepreneur brought equilibrium to a market by correctly predicting consumer preferences.[86]

Spatial economics deal with distance and area, and how these may affect a market through transportation costs and geographical limitations. The development of spatial economics is usually ascribed to German economist Johann Heinrich von Thünen; however, Cantillon addressed spatial economics nearly a century earlier.[87] Cantillon integrated his advancements in spatial economic theory into his microeconomic analysis of the market, describing how transportation costs influence the location of factories, markets and population centres—that is, individuals strive to lower transportation costs.[88] Conclusions on spatial economics were derived from three premises: cost of raw materials of equal quality will always be higher near the capital city, due to transportation costs; transportation costs vary on transportation type (for example, water transportation was, and often still is, cheaper than land-based transportation); and larger goods that are more difficult to transport will always be cheaper closer to their area of production.[89] For example, Cantillon believed markets were designed as they were to decrease costs to both merchants and villagers in terms of time and transportation.[90] Similarly, Cantillon posited that the locations of cities were the result in large part of the wealth of inhabiting property owners and their ability to afford transportation costs—wealthier property owners tended to live farther from their property, because they could afford the transportation costs.[91] In Essai, spatial economic theory was used to derive why markets occupied the geographical area they did and why costs varied across different markets.[92]

Cover of the Ludwig von Mises Institute's edition of Cantillon's Essai

Apart from originating theories on the entrepreneur and spatial economics, Cantillon also provided a dedicated theory on population growth. Unlike William Petty, who believed there always existed a considerable amount of unused land and economic opportunity to support economic growth, Cantillon theorised that population grows only as long as there are economic opportunities present.[93] Specifically, Cantillon cited three determining variables for population size: natural resources, technology, and culture.[94] Therefore, populations grow only as far as the three aforementioned variables allowed.[95] Furthermore, Cantillon's population theory was more modern than that of Malthus in the sense that Cantillon recognised a much broader category of factors which affect population growth, including the tendency for population growth to fall to zero as a society becomes more industrialised.[96]

Influence

While the Essai was not published until 1755 as a result of heavy censorship in France, it did widely circulate in the form of an unpublished manuscript between its completion and its publication.[97] It notably influenced many direct forerunners of the classical school of thought, including Turgot and other physiocrats.[98] Cantillon was a major influence on physiocrat François Quesnay, who has probably had access to his work through the marquis de Mirabeau, who possessed a manuscript of the Essai since 1740.[99][100] While it is evident that the Essai influenced Quesnay, to what degree remains controversial. There is evidence that Quesnay did not fully understand, or was not completely aware of, Cantillon's theories.[101] Many of Quesnay's economic beliefs were elucidated previously in the Essai,[102] but Quesnay did reject a number of Cantillon's premises, including the scarcity of land and Cantillon's population theory.[103] Also, Quesnay recognised the scarcity of capital and capital accumulation as a prerequisite for investment.[101] Nevertheless, Cantillon was considered the "father of physiocracy" by Henry Higgs, due to his influence on Quesnay.[104] It is also possible that Cantillon influenced Scottish economist James Steuart, both directly and indirectly.[105]

Cantillon is one of the few economists cited by Adam Smith, who directly borrows Cantillon's subsistence theory of wages.[5][106] Large sections of Smith's economic theory were possibly directly influenced by Cantillon, although in many respects Adam Smith advanced well beyond the scope of Cantillon.[107] Some economic historians have argued that Adam Smith provided little of value from his own intellect, notably Schumpeter[5][108] and Rothbard.[109] In any case, through his influence on Adam Smith and the physiocrats, Cantillon was quite possibly the pre-classical economist who contributed most to the ideas of the classical school.[110] Illustrative of this was Cantillon's influence on Jean-Baptiste Say, which is noticeable in the methodology employed in the latter's Treatise on Political Economy.[5][111]

References

  1. 1 2 Brewer 1992, p. 2; Brewer notes two suggested dates of birth, but puts greater weight on the validity of Antoine Murphy's estimate, "Murphy thinks that Cantillon was probably born in the 1680s, at Ballyronan in County Kerry, Ireland; Walsh says that he was born in 1697 (which is hard to square with the fact that he was in a position of responsibility in 1711)". Spengler August 1954, p. 283; Spengler cites Hone and mentions the same uncertainty in Cantillon's date as birth, "He was born in Ireland, in March 1697, according to Hone, and some seven to seventeen years earlier according to others."
  2. 1 2 Rothbard 1995, p. 347; Hayek 1991, p. 246; Higgs 1891, p. 290
  3. 1 2 Jevons 1881, p. 342; writes Jevons, "Cantillon's essay is, more emphatically than any other single work, 'the cradle of political economy.'" Cantillon 2010, p. 15; Editors Mark Thornton and Chantal Saucier write, "The influence of Cantillon's manuscript was largely unknown and the book had fallen so far into neglect that William Stanley Jevons was said to have "rediscovered" it in the late 19th century."
  4. 1 2 Cantillon 2010, p. 15
  5. 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 Nevin, Seamus (2013). "Richard Cantillon: The Father of Economics". History Ireland. 21 (2): 20–23. JSTOR 41827152.
  6. Spengler August 1954, p. 283; writes Spengler, "Much of the life of Richard Cantillon, author of the Essai, remains enveloped in mystery."
  7. Higgs 1891, p. 270; Higgs cites the so-called Burke's Heraldic Illustrations, 1845, plate 51.
  8. Brewer 1992, p. 2; Higgs 1891, pp. 271–272
  9. Brewer 1992, p. 2
  10. Finegold September 2010; "Paymaster General James Brydges was a very wealthy man with much influence, which allowed Cantillon to make political and business connections before again leaving for France in 1714."
  11. Brewer 1992, p. 4; Finegold September 2010; Rothbard 1995, p. 345
  12. Brewer 1992, p. 4; Finegold September 2010
  13. Rothbard 1995, p. 345; writes Rothbard, "Moreover, Richard's mother's uncle, Sir Daniel Arthur, was a prominent banker in London and Paris ..."
  14. Brewer 1992, pp. 4–5
  15. Rothbard 1995, pp. 345–346; Brewer 1992, p. 5
  16. Potter, William (1650). "The Key of Wealth". England: Johnson Reprint Corp.
  17. Rothbard 1995, pp. 327–330; Finegold September 2010
  18. Brewer 1992, pp. 5–6; Finegold September 2010
  19. Brewer 1992, p. 6; Finegold September 2010; Rothbard 1995, pp. 329, 345–346
  20. Brewer 1992, p. 6; writes Brewer, "He was introduced to Law at an early stage ... Most important, he bought shares early and sold at a large profit, thinking that the scheme was unsound and was bound to fail." Brewer also notes that Cantillon was acting as John Law's personal banker, at the time.
  21. 1 2 Higgs 1891, 276; Cantillon's reply is according to Higgs, who records Law as follows: "His great credit during the Regency aroused the jealousy of John Law, who held blunt language with him: 'I can send you to the Bastille to-night if you don't give me your word to quit the kingdom in four and twenty hours!'"
  22. Finegold September 2010; Rothbard 1995, p. 346
  23. Brewer 1992, p. 7; Brewer suggests that Cantillon stored his wealth in London to avoid high French taxes levied on those who had profited from the speculative bubble. Hyse 1971, p. 815; Hyse writes that profits were remitted both to London and Amsterdam, "The English records indicate that Cantillon remitted his speculative profits from Paris to Amsterdam and London."
  24. Rothbard 1995, p. 346; Rothbard notes that these high interest rates incorporated an inflation premium.
  25. Brewer 1992, pp. 7–8; Rothbard 1995, pp. 346–347
  26. Higgs 1891, pp. 282–283; Rothbard 1995, pp. 346–347
  27. Higgs 1871, pp. 282, 288
  28. Higgs 1891, p. 286; Spengler August 1954, p. 284
  29. Brewer 1992, p. 8
  30. Brewer 1992, p. 8; Brewer restates Murphy's argument, where Murphy cites the fact that the so-called Chevalier de Louvigny carried a large number of documents related to Cantillon.
  31. Brewer 1992, p. 9
  32. Cantillon 2010, p. 13; In the introduction to the Ludwig von Mises Institute's 2010 edition of Essai, Mark Thornton and Chantal Saucier write, "Based on the book itself and other evidence, we are now reasonably confident that Cantillon completed the manuscript in 1730." Brewer, p. 9
  33. Spengler August 1954, p. 61; Essai was published roughly twenty-one years after Cantillon's death.
  34. Hone 1994, p. 96
  35. Jevons 1881, pp. 341–343; writes Jevons, "The Essai is far more than a mere essay or even collection of disconnected essays like those of Hume. It is a systematic and connected treatise, going over in a concise manner nearly the whole field of economics, with the exception of taxation." Rothbard 1995, p. 345; Cantillon 2010, p. 13; Brewer 1992, p. 11
  36. Cantillon 2010, p. 5
  37. 1 2 Schumpeter 1954, p. 210; Schumpeter states, "What Petty failed to accomplish—but for what he had offered almost all the essential ideas—lies accomplished before us in Cantillon's Essai."
  38. Jevons 1881, p. 343; Like Cantillon, Petty proposed that the value of an object was the aggregate of the land and labor involved in its production.
  39. Brewer 1992, p. 15; Brewer states, "I shall argue that Cantillon took very little from Petty, and that he completely remade the little that he did take." Schumpeter 1954, p. 210; Schumpeter concedes, "True, it was not accomplished in the style of a pupil who at every step looks back over his shoulder for the master's guidance, but in the style of an intellectual peer who strides along confidently according to his own lights."
  40. Brewer 1992, p. 15
  41. Higgs 1892, p. 437
  42. Hyse 1971, p. 823
  43. Salerno 1985, p. 305
  44. Hayek 1991, pp. 259–60
  45. 1 2 Rothbard 1995, p. 348
  46. Hayek 1991, pp. 260–261; Cantillon 2010, pp. 70–71; an example Cantillon's use of ceteris paribus can be found in chapter twelve, part one, of Essai, "The land belongs to the owners but would be useless to them if it were not cultivated. The more labor is expended on it, other things being equal, the more it produces ..."
  47. Finegold June 2010; Carl Menger is credited with providing the Austrian School the methodological insight which would lead to Ludwig von Mises's development of praxeology.
  48. Salerno 1985, p. 306
  49. Hayek 1991, p. 260
  50. Brewer 1988; Thornton December 2007; Thornton 2007
  51. Brewer 1988, p. 447
  52. Thornton 2007, p. 4; Mark Thornton writes, "When this handful of selected quotes is placed into the proper historical and textual context they can even take on the possibility of being arguments against mercantilism and for a more laissez faire economy."
  53. Finegold September 2010; writes Finegold, "Cantillon's insights on the source of economic wealth also set him apart from typical mercantilists before him."
  54. Cantillon 2010, p. 21; Editors Mark Thornton and Chantal Saucier provide an abstract, stating, "Cantillon defines wealth as the consumption goods produced by land and labor. This contrasted with the Mercantilists who thought money was wealth."
  55. Rothbard 1995, pp. 349–350; Cantillon 2010, pp. 53–56
  56. Rothbard 1995, pp. 349–350; Cantillon 2010, p. 55; writes Cantillon, "But it often happens that many things, which actually have a certain intrinsic value, are not sold in the market according to that value; that will depend on the desires and moods of men, and on their consumption."
  57. Hülsmann 2002, p. 696
  58. Cantillon 2010, p. 119; "The price of meat will be determined after some bargaining, and a pound of beef will be valued in silver [i.e., money] approximately the same as all beef offered for sale in the market [i.e., supply], is to all the silver brought there to buy beef [i.e., demand]."
  59. Cantillon 2010, p. 119; Finegold September 2010; Tarascio 1985, p. 252
  60. Cantillon 2010, p. 66
  61. Cantillon 2010, p. 148; "Mr. Locke lays it does as a fundamental maxim that the quantity of goods in proportion to the quantity of money is a regulator of market prices. I have tried to elucidate his idea in the preceding chapters: he had clearly seen that the abundance of money makes everything more expensive, but he has not considered how this happens. The great difficulty of this question consists in knowing in what way and in what proportion the increase of money raises the prices of things."
  62. Rothbard 1995, p. 355
  63. Rothbard 1995, p. 356
  64. Cantillon 2010, p. 155; Bordo 1983, p. 242
  65. "How Cantillon Effect Works In 5 Steps (Top 2024 Dangers)". Swan Bitcoin. Retrieved 13 December 2023.
  66. Cantillon 2010, pp. 147–148
  67. Bordo 1983, p. 237
  68. Spengler October 1954, pp. 414–415
  69. Cantillon 2010, pp. 227–30
  70. 1 2 Rothbard 1995, p. 359
  71. Spengler October 1954, p. 418; Rothbard 1995, pp. 358–359
  72. Bordo 1983, p. 244
  73. Brewer 1992, p. 114
  74. Brewer 1992, pp. 117–118
  75. Hayek 1991, p. 265; Hayek notes that Cantillon's theory of interest was overlooked by Eugen von Böhm-Bawerk, who wrote Capital and Interest as a critique of existing theories of interest in order to set up the introduction of his own time-preference theory of interest. This is meant to illustrate the obscurity of Cantillon's Essai to the economics profession prior to its "rediscovery" by Jevons.
  76. Cantillon 2010, pp. 169–170
  77. Cantillon 2010, pp. 170–171
  78. Bordo 1983, p. 247; Brewer 1992, p. 91
  79. Hayek 1991, pp. 265–266
  80. Bordo 1983, pp. 247–248, 253
  81. Brewer 1992, p. 51; Anthony Brewer, however, distinguishes between Say's and Cantillon's use of the term "entrepreneur", noting that while Cantillon saw the entrepreneur as a risk-taker, Say predominately considered the entrepreneur a "planner".
  82. Rothbard 1995, p. 351; Hülsmann 2002, p. 698. Hülsmann argues that Cantillon divided society into four classes: politicians, property owners, entrepreneurs, and wage-earners.
  83. Tarascio 1985, p. 251
  84. Cantillon 2010, p. 74; "They [entrepreneurs] pay a fixed price for them at the place where they are purchased, to resell wholesale or retail at an uncertain price ... These entrepreneurs never know how great the demand will be in their city ..."
  85. Tarascio 1985, pp. 251–252
  86. Rothbard 1995, p. 352
  87. Hébert 1981, p. 71
  88. Rothbard 1995, p. 354
  89. Hébert 1981, p. 72
  90. Cantillon 2010, pp. 31–32
  91. Cantillon 2010, pp. 35–36
  92. Hébert 1981, p. 75
  93. Brewer 1992, p. 36; Brewer notes that Cantillon's theory on population was nearly identical to that of Malthus, who presented his own theory decades after Cantillon's death.
  94. Tarascio 1985, pp. 249–250
  95. Rothbard 1995, p. 353
  96. Tarascio 1985, pp. 250–251
  97. Rothbard 1995, p. 360
  98. Rothbard 1995, pp. 360–361
  99. Bertholet, Auguste (2020). "The intellectual origins of Mirabeau". History of European Ideas. 47: 91–96. doi:10.1080/01916599.2020.1763745. S2CID 219747599.
  100. Schumpeter 1954, pp. 209–210; writes Schumpeter, "Cantillon's great work fared better both because of its well-rounded systematic or even didactic form and because it had the good fortune to gain, long before its actual publication, the enthusiastic approval and the effective support of two very influential men, Gournay and Mirabeau." Furthermore, Schumpeter establishes, "An analogy may be helpful: Cantillon was to Quesnay, and Petty was to Cantillon, what Ricardo was to Marx."
  101. 1 2 Brewer 1992, p. 168; Brewer cites a conversation between Quesnay and Mirabeau, as chronicled by the latter.
  102. Brewer 1992, pp. 174–175
  103. Brewer 1992, pp. 159–175
  104. Higgs 1892, p. 454
  105. Brewer 1992, p. 175; Brewer cites Steuart's reference to a tract by Phillip Cantillon, which in turn was based largely on Essai, and the many similarities between Steuart's Inquiry into the Principles of Political Oeconomy and Cantillon's Essai.
  106. Smith 2009, p. 45; "Mr. Cantillon seems, upon this account, to suppose that the lowest species of common labourers must everywhere earn at least double their own maintenance, in order that, one with another, they may be enabled to bring up two children." Cantillon 2010, pp. 59–65; Marx 2007, p. 608, n. 1
  107. Brewer 1992, pp. 192–193
  108. Schumpeter 1954, p. 179; Schumpeter charged, "But no matter what he actually learned or failed to learn from predecessors, the fact is that the Wealth of Nations does not contain a single analytic idea, principle, or method that was entirely new in 1776."
  109. Rothbard 1995, p. 435; Rothbard wrote, "The problem is that he originated nothing that was true, and that whatever he originated was wrong; that, even in an age that had fewer citations or footnotes than our own, Adam Smith was a shameless plagiarist, acknowledging little or nothing and stealing large chunks, for example, from Cantillon."
  110. Hayek 1991, p. 246
  111. Salerno 1985, p. 312

Bibliography

This article is issued from Wikipedia. The text is licensed under Creative Commons - Attribution - Sharealike. Additional terms may apply for the media files.