Zvi Galor
Born1939 (age 8485)
Kfar Vitkin, Israel
Alma materTel Aviv University
Hebrew University of Jerusalem
Bar-Ilan University
Scientific career
InstitutionsInternational Institute of the Histadrut

Dr. Zvi Galor (צבי גלאור), born in 1939, is an Israeli expert on cooperatives.[1]

Biography

Born in 1939 in Kfar Vitkin,[2] Zvi Galor earned his bachelor's degree from Tel Aviv University in 1966. In 1987 he obtained his master's degree from the Hebrew University of Jerusalem, graduating with honors, and in 2017, at the age of 78, received his doctoral degree[3] from Bar-Ilan University in Ramat-Gan. From 1980 to 2002, Galor served as the pedagogical director of the English and French internships at the International Institute for Labour, Development and Cooperative Studies in Tel Aviv (ILDEC),[4] which in 1994 became part of the International Institute of the Histadrut.[5] This institute provides trainees from countries all over the world with advanced training sessions in cooperative management and development. In 1996 Zvi Galor became the institute's academic director,[6] In this position he initiated dozens of pedagogical overseas missions in situ, organizing training courses run by the institute's instructors directly in the students' country of origin. These projects took place in Africa, Asia, Europe, South America and Oceania.

Development activities

From 1976 to 1978, Galor participated in the establishment of a moshav in the Jordan Valley.[7] He was also a member of Moshav Kfar Vitkin's Executive Committee from 1978 to 1980. Since his retirement, Galor has been involved in the creation of many cooperative projects in both developing and developed countries[3][8][9][10] working mainly as a consultant. His writings and research have served as a guideline for these projects, particularly for the creation of cooperatives in rural areas and the development of these regions.

Research activities

Zvi Galor has developed an innovative research axis aimed at preventing the dismantling of cooperatives.[11] These ideas were best encapsulated[12] in the conclusions of the Seminar of Leaders of the Mauritius Cooperative Movement (Macoscle), led by Galor,[13] as well as in the establishment of the charter of the "Oklahoma Food Cooperative Project" in Oklahoma, USA.[3] Zvi Galor has published dozens of articles he wrote in Hebrew in English and in French, some of which were even translated into Spanish, Arabic, Indonesian and Vietnamese[14][15][3][16]

Principles developed by Zvi Galor

  • The cooperative[17] is created by its founding members,[18] and is the exclusive property of the members.[19]
  • The cooperative is established in order to serve its members optimally[20] and at the lowest possible cost.[21]
  • The value of the common property[22] is equal to the sum of the shares held by the members of the cooperative.[23]
  • Cooperatives strive to operate at cost price,[24] i.e. they do not generate any profits or losses. Any profits or surpluses[25] are distributed equitably among members in the current year, based on their participation. Occasional losses are covered by all members according to their participation.[26]

Study of "decooperativisation"

Zvi Galor studied the problems arising from the dismantling of cooperative structures (decooperativisation),[27] both in developing and developed countries. He focused in particular on the reasons that led to the dismantling of two Israeli cooperatives that had been in existence for a relatively long period: Tnuva and Hamashbir Hamerkazi.[28] Tnuva[29][30] is an example of a secondary cooperative.[31][32] For the 80 years of its existence, it served as a platform for the marketing of dairy and agricultural products. It comprised all the moshavim and kibbutzim in Israel.

Factors that lead to the dismantling of a cooperative

Galor found that the following situations lead to the dismantling of a cooperative:

  • A cooperative whose members have mostly stopped using the services it offers is more exposed to the risk of decooperation.[33]
  • A cooperative whose shares are held at nominal value[34][35][36] recognizes the risk that its members will demand for themselves the unallocated collective value of the structure.[37][38]
  • A cooperative whose members are not always aware of the real value of their cooperative equity, the assets of which they are seeking to sell. Potential buyers often finance the cost of buying a cooperative by reselling its assets.[39]

See also

References

  1. Zvi Galor is a member of the editorial board of the Revue internationale de l'économie sociale (RECMA) as a foreign academic correspondent
  2. Zvi Galor describes the cooperative components of the moshav in general and his own moshav, Kfar Vitkin in this article: The cooperative components of the Classic Moshav in Journal of Co-operative Organization and Management. 2:2, 83–91, 2014
  3. 1 2 3 4 "Follicles of Unwanted Hair" (PDF). Coopgalor.com. Retrieved 12 April 2022.
  4. "International Institute for Labour, Development and Cooperative Studies | UIA Yearbook Profile". Uia.org.
  5. "International Institute of the Histadrut | UIA Yearbook Profile". Uia.org.
  6. "Archived copy". Archived from the original on 6 March 2019. Retrieved 6 March 2019.{{cite web}}: CS1 maint: archived copy as title (link)
  7. "The Moshav in Israel: An Agricultural Community in a Process of Change – A Current View". ResearchGate.net. Retrieved 12 April 2022.
  8. "Lutte contre le chômage : Coopec-Galor a remis des chèques à cinq jeunes promoteurs". Lefaso.net. Retrieved 12 April 2022.
  9. "POT-POURRI : Gouvernement / syndicats, les négociations reprennent le 15 novembre". Lefaso.net. Retrieved 12 April 2022.
  10. "About Us | Oklahoma Food Cooperative". Archived from the original on 26 December 2018. Retrieved 24 December 2018.
  11. "The Cooperative Business Movement, 1950 to the Present | Economic history". Cambridge University Press. Retrieved 12 April 2022.
  12. Zerfeshewa, Betru (12 June 2010). "Determinants of Saving and Credit Cooperatives (SACCOs) Operational Performance in Gondar town, Ethiopia". Opendocs.ids.ac.uk. Retrieved 12 April 2022.
  13. Fitriyah, N. (2018) Productive Resources Management: How Visiana Bhakti Cooperative Samarinda Strives. Journal of Social Studies Education Research, 9:2, 189–209. "Globally, though such cooperatives often fail to satisfy their members’ needs, members and administrators are rarely able to comprehend the problems in question. (Galor, 2013). Galor (2013), Movsisyam (2013), and Friedman (1992) suggest trust is the most important element when seeking credit."
  14. "Zvi Galor". Researchgate.net. Retrieved 12 April 2022.
  15. "Zvi Galor". Scholar.google.com. Retrieved 12 April 2022.
  16. "לעבדה ולשמרה קואופרטיב חקלאות ציונית". Archived from the original on 11 April 2019. Retrieved 2 June 2022.
  17. "According to Galor (2003:1), co-operatives are economic enterprises that are initiated by their members and belong entirely to their members. These enterprises are formed with the intention of providing the best possible services at the lowest possible cost to their members when markets fail to provide required goods and services at affordable prices and acceptable quality." in Simelane, N. (2011). An assessment of the role of co-operatives in smallholder dairy production and marketing in Swaziland. Supervised by Prof. J. Kirsten, For the degree of Msc. Agric., University of Pretoria, Department of Agricultural Economics, Extension and Rural Development Faculty of Natural and Agricultural Sciences, 1–136, Pretoria. p. 14-15.
  18. Mikami, K. (2018) Are cooperative firms a less competitive form of business? Production efficiency and financial viability of cooperative firms with tradable membership shares. Economic Systems, 42:3, P. 501 7.3. Israeli community cooperatives (15): "The final example is neither a worker nor consumer cooperative. A moshav is an agricultural community cooperative in Israel. A moshav conducts a wide range of activities for member residents of the community, from the collective purchasing of farm inputs and the collective marketing of agricultural products to savings, credit and insurance, the retail of food and household goods, and even public administration. One distinguishing feature of a moshav is that its farmland is divided into farm lots of equal size, 3 ha on average, and its membership is tied to the right to use a single lot. Because the total area of farmland in the village is fixed and the farm lots are not allowed to be combined or subdivided, the number of memberships is constant over time. Membership is usually inherited by one of the member’s children. However, childless members can sell their membership to farmers outside the village at the market price or for the real value of the share capital. Along with the kibbutz, another type of community cooperative in Israel, the moshav has been prevalent in rural areas throughout the country over the past century. The system of the moshav seems to provide another indication that closed membership is the key feature required for a market for membership shares to function well." (15) This subsection is based on Galor (2014, 2015a,b) and additional information obtained from the author. Galor, Z., 2014. The cooperative components of the classic moshav. J. Co-Operative Org. Manage. 2, 83–91. Galor, Z., 2015a. Equity in service at cost: the case of the classic moshav. J. Co-Operative Stud. 48, 28–37. Galor, Z., 2015b. Le mochav classique et ses départements en Israël. Rev. Internationale de L’économie Sociale (336), pp. 94–103
  19. "Microsoft Word - OklahomaFood.doc". Archive.wikiwix.com. Retrieved 12 April 2022.
  20. Kigathi, Carmeline C. Wambui (12 April 2016). "Motivating factors for dairy cooperative membership in Kenya : a case of small holder dairy farmers in Kiambu County". Su-plus.strathmore.edu. Retrieved 12 April 2022.
  21. "Archived copy" (PDF). Archived from the original (PDF) on 10 June 2010. Retrieved 24 December 2018.{{cite web}}: CS1 maint: archived copy as title (link)
  22. Draperi, J. (2000). Les organisations coopératives et mutualistes face au marché et à la déréglementation. Revue internationale de l'économie sociale, (278), 4–4. doi:10.7202/1023845ar "Enfin, Zvi Galor retrace la grande aventure des coopératives d’épargne et de crédit d’Israël, de leur création au début du Xxe siècle jusqu’à nos jours. S’appuyant parfois sur des sources inédites (comme un entretien avec Abraham Brener, ancien directeur de l’importante coopérative de crédit et d’épargne de Tel-Aviv), Zvi Galor montre l’importance de ce mouvement. S’attachant à détailler les règles de l’organisation de l’épargne et du crédit, il met en évidence la place de ces coopératives dans le développement, avant qu’elles ne se fédèrent et, finalement, se transforment en banques coopératives."
  23. Mikami, K. (2018)
  24. "The deficit or surplus was allocated among District members based on a per-acre availability charge for water in accord with IID policy" Cited in P. 45 in Rosen, M. D., & Sexton, R. J. (1993) Irrigation districts and water markets: An application of cooperative decision-making theory. Land Economics, 69:1, pp. 39–53
  25. L’économie sociale : économique parce que sociale Jean-François Draperi – Revue internationale de l'économie sociale, Number 336, April 2015 "Zvi Galor se penche sur une question peu étudiée, celle de la comptabilité et de la gestion originale des mochavs, villages coopératifs israéliens. L’auteur souligne les aspects les plus remarquables de cette comptabilité : la distinction entre la participation aux frais d’immobilisation et la participation au fonctionnement ou encore l’absence de déficit ou de surplus dans toute comptabilité. La conjugaison de ces deux caractères met en évidence l’articulation originale entre la solidarité coopérative et l’intérêt de chaque membre."
  26. Battilani, Patrizia; Schröter, Harm G. (27 August 2012). The Cooperative Business Movement, 1950 to the Present. Cambridge University Press. p. 152. ISBN 9781107028982. Retrieved 12 April 2022 via Google Books.
  27. Subject of Zvi Galor's doctoral thesis
  28. Zvi Galor. "Demutualization of Cooperatives: the Case Study of Tnuva" (PDF). Departments.agri.huji.ac.il. Retrieved 12 April 2022.
  29. "TnuvaDemutENG25.8.08.mellel". Archive.wikiwix.com. Retrieved 12 April 2022.
  30. "Model of Secondary and Tertiary Cooperatives as Support of the Primary Cooperative". Findevgateway.org. Retrieved 12 April 2022.
  31. "Finance and Guarantees in Rural Development". Findevgateway.org. Retrieved 12 April 2022.
  32. "Archived copy" (PDF). Archived from the original (PDF) on 7 October 2018. Retrieved 24 December 2018.{{cite web}}: CS1 maint: archived copy as title (link)
  33. "Caravane coopérative du 20 juin 2016" (PDF). Caravanecooperative.be. Retrieved 12 April 2022.
  34. "Archived copy" (PDF). Archived from the original (PDF) on 6 October 2018. Retrieved 24 December 2018.{{cite web}}: CS1 maint: archived copy as title (link)
  35. Mauget, R. (2008). Les coopératives agricoles : Un atout pour la pérennité de l’agriculture dans la mondialisation. Revue internationale de l'économie sociale, (307), p. 54
  36. "Archived copy" (PDF). Archived from the original (PDF) on 21 September 2018. Retrieved 24 December 2018.{{cite web}}: CS1 maint: archived copy as title (link)
  37. Galor, Z., & Sofer, M. (2011) Evolution passée et récente des villages coopératifs en Israël. Recma – Revue Internationale de l’Economie Sociale, 321, pp. 19–21. Juillet, 2011
  38. See Gideon Bickel, and also: Zvi Galor's doctoral thesis : interview of Gideon Bickel (2017)
This article is issued from Wikipedia. The text is licensed under Creative Commons - Attribution - Sharealike. Additional terms may apply for the media files.