Demeny voting (or family voting[1]) is a type of proxy voting where the provision of a political voice for children by allowing parents or guardians to vote on their behalf. The term is named after demographer Paul Demeny even though the concept predates him[2] and is often pitched as a stop-gap measure for whatever ages suffrage is denied to youth.[3] Under a Demeny voting system, parents would decide how to cast each child's proxy vote, and some systems could allow for a split vote if the parents' political views differ. Children would gain the right to vote either at a certain voting age or when they feel they are ready.[4]
Etymology
Demeny voting is named after demographer Paul Demeny. Demeny argued that children "should not be left disenfranchised for some 18 years: let custodial parents exercise the children's voting rights until they come of age". Demeny's motivation behind proposing such a system was to "make the political system more responsive to the young generation's interests" and was part of a broader set of policy proposals aimed at combating the low fertility rate in certain countries.[5]
History
The idea, however, is older than Demeny's idea; it was regularly discussed in France in the 1920s and was almost adopted by the National Assembly.[6][7]
In Germany the idea was even first discussed in the 1910s.[8] In the 1970s and the 1980s lawyers and political scientists began a discussion which is still going on. In 2003 and 2008 the German parliament had votes on whether to introduce a Kinderwahlrecht (which is the term in German), but the proposals were defeated.[9] In 2011 Hermann started a comprehensive economic approach to discuss it.[10]
Pieter Vanhuysse (head of research and Deputy Director at the European Centre for Social Welfare Policy and Research, Vienna) argued in 2013 that in Austria, where there are relatively strong pro-elderly policies, that "the time is ripe for at least opening a clear-headed and empirically informed democratic debate about the radical idea of giving each parent one half extra vote, to be used on behalf of each under-age child until that child reaches legal voting age".[11]
Japan has discussed Demeny voting as a possible answer to its aging population, which gives disproportionate voice to the elderly as a result of their increasing numbers. This follows the publication of a paper by Reiko Aoki of the Centre for Intergenerational Studies at Hitotsubashi University and Rhema Vaithianathan of the University of Auckland.[12] On 2 March 2011, the Centre for Intergenerational Studies at Hitotsubashi University hosted a conference on Demeny voting.[13] Aoki and Vaithianathan have also conducted a number of surveys on voter attitude to Demeny Voting and found that a considerable percentage of respondents would cast their children's vote differently to their own. In July 2013, Nikkei in Japan wrote a major editorial supporting the idea as part of a debate on constitutional reform in Japan.
In Hungary, the ruling coalition has been advocating Demeny voting, but admitted in April 2011 that it probably won't come into practice for some time.[14]
Paul Demeny discussed the idea on a CBC interview.[15] Professor Miles Corak from the University of Ottawa has also written a blog on the idea and promoted it in Canada. He suggests that it is supported on a humanitarian basis since the UN Convention on the Rights of the Child provides that children be given civil and political rights. He suggests that given the evidence that households where mothers control the purse-strings spend more on their children, it is mothers who ought to be given the proxy vote until the child comes of age. Professor Corak's thesis has been taken up by journalist-turned-politician Chrystia Freeland.
Arguments in favor
Aoki and Vaithianathan argue that Demeny voting is justified because it reduces gerontocracy. They calculate that Demeny voting in Japan would increase the parent voting bloc from 24% to 37% and lower the over-55-year-old voter-bloc from 43% to 35%.[16]
Stefan Olsson[17] argues that "the delegation of the children's right to vote is not any stranger than when adults delegate political authority to their elected representative. After the election, the representatives have the right to make use of this authority." (page 71). He suggests that delegating a child's authority to the parent is perfectly reasonable. Olsson also argues that there are other areas where parents are delegated authority such as what the child eats, where he goes to school, and children are regularly represented in a court of law by parents. He says that "Arguing that parents cannot act as their children's representative because they might abuse their position becomes absurd in comparison to all the other powers parents already have over their children." (page 72).
It has been suggested it would make it harder for elderly voters to vote in governments that borrow money for social security but which will only be paid back by future generations.[18] It may ensure that the needs of children, such as education, childcare, and healthcare, are better taken into account.[12][19] It could also make governments more ecologically conscious as younger people will be more affected by poor environmental policy than older voters. Finally, extending the vote to children may increase their involvement in politics, encouraging children to grow up and be more active citizens.
Arguments made against
Enfranchising children is preferable
Some writers argue that, like marrying or making a will, voting is an exercise of the informed will and cannot legitimately be done by proxy.[7] Some opponents see Demeny voting as a violation of a fundamental normative principle of democracy: 'one person, one vote'. They point to the fact that children below the minimum voting age can hold different political opinions and thus prefer different parties to their parents. There is no evidence that parents would split their votes. Instead, they would have plural votes for the same party they prefer (and have formerly preferred).
Yet others have argued that more youth suffrage, by lowering the voting age to 13 or 14 or lower would be more beneficial, as many children are able to express complex opinions at that age.[20][21] Further, law professor Vivian Hamilton argues that in light of findings from research in developmental psychology and cognitive and social neuroscience, governments can "no longer justify the electoral exclusion of mid-adolescents by claiming that they lack the relevant competencies."[22] In the United Kingdom, Politics professor David Runciman argues for lowering the voting age to 6.[23][24] Some scholars advocate a 'flexible voting age' building on the willingness of minors to participate in elections.[25] The ‘flexible voting age’ proposal contains a need for adolescents to register in voting lists and so differs from proposals that come under the name of ‘voting from birth on’ or ‘voting age zero’. It takes into account that infants, small children and many younger adolescents will have no interest in political participation.
Suffrage should only be for adults
Others have argued that with the right to vote comes other obligations of citizenship, such as military service.[26] Some people worry that the power of older votes will be diluted and the interests of children might be prioritised above those of the elderly.
Jon Elster has argued that if the justification for Demeny is on the basis of consequences, then said consequences should be voted on, rather than changing the voting demographic. His argument is that to advance Demeny voting on the grounds that it leads to desirable consequences is pointless, since it will be blocked by exactly those groups who will block the desired consequences (e.g. raising the pension age).[27]
Variations
In 1998, in "One Child, One Vote: Proxies for Parents", family law professor Jane Rutherford considered proxy voting on behalf of children as a means of achieving fair representation of their interests in political debate in the context of the United States. As criteria for who should hold proxies for children, she suggested the following: "(1) the representative should have a stake in a very substantial shared venture with the child; (2) the representative should be personally familiar with the needs and circumstances of the child; (3) the child should have ready and frequent access to the representative so the child can express herself in her own terms whenever possible; (4) the representative should be accountable to the child in some fashion, either emotionally or legally; and (5) the representative should share an emotional bond with the child that promotes caring, sympathy, and empathy."
In 2014, childhood studies professor John Wall put forward a proposal for proxy-claim suffrage, in which a child could actively claim their right to vote from their proxy-holder, rather than passively waiting for age-based voting qualification, in Why Children and Youth Should Have the Right to Vote: An Argument for Proxy-Claim Suffrage. He further developed this idea and its relation to childism in the book Give Children the Vote: on Democratizing Democracy. Wall co-founded the ongoing Children's Voting Colloquium with Robin Chen to bring together in virtual society discussants of minimum voting age reform.
See also
References
- ↑ Wall, John (2022). "Ch. 1: Voting over History". Give Children the Vote: On Democratizing Democracy. London, UK. ISBN 978-1-350-19630-8 OCLC 1262678642
- ↑ Gesley, Jenny (19 April 2018). "Family Voting as a Solution to Low Fertility? Experiences from France and Germany | In Custodia Legis". The Library of Congress. Retrieved 17 May 2023.
- ↑ Stone, Lyman (1 September 2021). "Opinion | The Minimum Voting Age Should Be Zero". The New York Times. ISSN 0362-4331. Retrieved 20 January 2023.
- ↑ Wall, John (2022). "Ch. 7: The Proxy-Claim Vote". Give Children the Vote: On Democratizing Democracy. London, UK. ISBN 978-1-350-19630-8. OCLC 1262678642.
{{cite book}}
: CS1 maint: location missing publisher (link) - ↑ Demeny, P. 1986 "Pronatalist Policies in Low-Fertility Countries: Patterns, Performance and Prospects," Population and Development Review, vol. 12 (supplement): 335–358.
- ↑ Parijs, Philippe van, 1999 ,"The Disenfranchisement of the Elderly, and Other Attempts to Secure Intergenerational Justice", Philosophy and Public Affairs, vol. 27,: 292–333.
- 1 2 Hinrichs, Karl, 2002,"Do the Old Exploit the Young? Is Enfranchising Children a Good Idea?", Archives of European Sociology Vol 23.
- ↑ Rupprecht, I. "Das Wahlrecht für Kinder", Baden-Baden 2012, Nomos-Verlag: 26–32
- ↑ "Wahlrecht für Kinder?".
- ↑ Hermann, U. "Ökonomische Analyse eines Kinderwahlrechts", Saarbrücken, südwestdeutscher verlag, http://www.diss.fu-berlin.de/diss/receive/FUDISS_thesis_000000021349?lang=en
- ↑ "A Snapshot of Intergenerational Justice - Downloads - European Centre for Social Welfare Policy and Research" (PDF).
- 1 2 EconPapers: Is Demeny Voting the Answer to Low Fertility in Japan?
- ↑ "一橋大学経済研究所 世代間問題研究機構 | 世代間問題研究会". Archived from the original on 31 January 2011. Retrieved 14 February 2011.
- ↑ Politics.hu, April 4th, 2011: "Fidesz official urges body set up to examine giving extra vote to families" Archived 11 March 2012 at the Wayback Machine Retrieved 2011-06-23
- ↑ CBC interview with Paul Demeny
- ↑ EconPapers: Is Demeny Voting the Answer to Low Fertility in Japan?
- ↑ Olsson, Stefan, 2008,"Children's Suffrage: A Critique of the Importance of Voters' Knowledge for the Well-Being of Democracy", The International Journal of Children's Rights, vol. 16,: 55–76.
- ↑ Should Parents Vote for Kids? | Tokyo Notes
- ↑ Sanderson, Warren (20 January 2008). "Low Fertility and Population Aging in Germany and Japan: Prospects and Policies" (PDF). Archived from the original (PDF) on 13 March 2012. Retrieved 30 January 2011.
- ↑ No Right Turn: Against Demeny voting
- ↑ No Right Turn: Lowering the voting age
- ↑ Hamilton, Vivian E. (2012). "Democratic Inclusion, Cognitive Development, and the Age of Electoral Majority". Rochester, NY. SSRN 2086875.
{{cite journal}}
: Cite journal requires|journal=
(help) - ↑ "Lower voting age to six to tackle bias against young, says academic". the Guardian. 6 December 2018. Retrieved 17 January 2023.
- ↑ "Votes for children! Why we should lower the voting age to six | David Runciman". the Guardian. 16 November 2021. Retrieved 17 January 2023.
- ↑ 5. Tremmel, Jörg / Wilhelm, James (2015): Democracy or Epistocracy? Age as a Criterion of Voter Eligibility. In: Tremmel, Jörg / Mason, Antony / Dimitrijoski, Igor / Godli, Petter (eds.): Youth Quotas in Ageing Societies. Dordrecht, NL: Springer, pp. 125–147.
- ↑ Schrag, F., 2004, "Children and Democracy: Theory and Practice Politics", Philosophy and Economics Vol 3
- ↑ Elster, Jon (1986) "Comment on van der Veen and Van Parijs", Theory and Society pp.709- 722